Rent control is a policy tool
designed to protect tenants from escalating housing costs by capping the amount
landlords can increase rent. While it benefits renters by promoting housing
stability, it poses significant challenges for property owners and the rental
housing market. Major cities such as Santa Monica, Los Angeles, San Francisco, New
York, and Washington D.C. have long experimented with rent control policies,
with varying results. As California voters prepare to revisit this debate with Proposition
33, it is essential to examine the broader impacts of rent control on property
owners and the availability of rental housing.
Impact on Property Owners
Rent control fundamentally alters
the economics of rental properties. For landlords and property owners, the
primary concerns include:
1. Reduced
Profitability: Rent control caps the amount by which rents can increase,
often not accounting for inflation, rising maintenance costs, or property
improvements. Property owners, especially those operating smaller units, may
struggle to maintain profitability. As a result, they may defer maintenance,
leading to deteriorating property conditions. In San Francisco and Santa Monica,
some landlords have reported difficulty in maintaining their properties due to
limited rent growth, impacting the overall quality of the housing stock.
2. Incentive to Sell or
Convert: In cities like New York and Los Angeles, some property owners,
faced with declining profits, choose to sell their properties or convert them
into condominiums. The rental market shrinks as units are taken off the market,
which paradoxically worsens the housing shortage. In Washington D.C.,
rent-controlled buildings have increasingly been converted into co-ops or
market-rate condominiums, as property owners try to capitalize on rising real
estate values in ways that are not restricted by rent caps.
3. Legal and Bureaucratic
Hurdles: Rent control policies often come with a complex set of regulations
that property owners must navigate. In Los Angeles, for example, landlords must
adhere to specific rules when raising rents, evicting tenants, or renovating
units. These regulations can add additional costs, especially for smaller
landlords who may lack the resources to manage the administrative burden.
4. Disincentive to Improve
Properties: In rent-controlled areas, landlords may have little financial
incentive to invest in property upgrades because they are unable to charge
higher rents to offset these costs. Over time, this can lead to a decline in
the overall quality of housing in rent-controlled cities like San Francisco,
where aging properties remain locked in rent-controlled agreements that fail to
account for significant capital improvements.
Impact on Availability of Rental Housing
1. Supply Constraints:
Rent control can reduce the availability of new rental units. Developers may be
reluctant to invest in rental housing in cities with strict rent control
policies because of concerns about limited returns on investment. In San
Francisco and Santa Monica, where stringent rent control has been in place for
decades, the construction of new rental housing has slowed considerably.
Instead, developers often pivot toward building luxury condos or units aimed at
higher-income tenants not subject to rent control.
2. Reduced Mobility: Rent
control creates a situation where long-term tenants, enjoying below-market
rates, are reluctant to move, even if they would otherwise choose to do so.
This locks units out of the market, reducing mobility and making it more
difficult for new renters to find housing. In New York, for example,
rent-controlled units can remain occupied for generations, leaving newer
residents facing a scarcity of available apartments.
3. Distorted Market Dynamics:
The mismatch between supply and demand in rent-controlled areas can lead to
informal market distortions, such as illegal subletting. Tenants in
rent-controlled units may rent out rooms or sublet entire apartments at market
rates, bypassing rent control regulations. In Washington D.C., anecdotal
evidence suggests that subletting at above-regulation rates is a common
practice, which further exacerbates housing inequities.
4. Rental Market Polarization:
Rent control often creates a divide between two segments of the rental market:
rent-controlled units and market-rate units. Rent-controlled tenants enjoy
significantly lower rents, while market-rate tenants face inflated prices as
landlords seek to compensate for their controlled units. This phenomenon has
been observed in Los Angeles and San Francisco, where market rents skyrocket,
particularly in neighborhoods where rent-controlled units are more
concentrated.
Proposition 33 and the Future of Rent Control in
California
Proposition 33, a ballot
initiative in California, seeks to expand rent control by repealing the Costa-Hawkins
Rental Housing Act, which currently limits rent control to buildings
constructed before 1995. If passed, the proposition would allow cities like Los
Angeles, Santa Monica, and San Francisco to implement rent control on a wider
range of buildings, including newer developments.
Supporters argue that expanding
rent control will help alleviate the housing affordability crisis by protecting
tenants from skyrocketing rents. However, opponents caution that Proposition 33
could exacerbate the state’s housing shortage by discouraging new development.
Developers may opt to invest in other states or focus on non-rental properties,
further constricting the rental market. Landlords, facing the prospect of
reduced returns, may also withdraw existing units from the rental market
through conversions to ownership models like condominiums.
Balancing Tenant Protections and Housing Supply
Rent control remains a deeply
polarizing issue, particularly in high-demand cities such as Los Angeles, San
Francisco, and New York. On one hand, it provides essential protections for
tenants against displacement and unaffordable rent increases. On the other
hand, it poses significant economic challenges for property owners and
contributes to the overall scarcity of rental housing.
As California considers Proposition
33, the state faces a difficult balancing act: How to ensure that tenants are
protected while also encouraging the construction of new housing to meet
demand. The challenge lies in creating policies that both promote housing
stability for renters and foster a healthy, dynamic housing market.
Ultimately, any long-term
solution will likely require a combination of tenant protections, incentives
for developers, and creative housing policies that increase the overall supply
of affordable housing.
Financing Properties
in Rent Controlled Markets
When considering the purchase or
refinancing of a residential unit in a rent-controlled apartment complex, a
property owner is likely to have difficulty. Lenders are keenly aware of the
economic limitations imposed by rent control, and the long-term effects of such
legislation do not account for any controls on inflation and other operating
costs of buildings.
As these costs increase,
operating income reduces or is eliminated, making the proposition a cash drain
for the property owner. As such, rent control introduces a new level of risk to
multifamily financing in these areas.
We have experienced many lenders
pulling funding from California residential properties until the results of the
upcoming election are known. If Prop 33 passes, multifamily property owners may
find that their funding options diminish, become more costly, or potentially
cease to exist.
The danger comes from political
advertisements that do not adequately explain the risks to renters that are
posed by rent control, as discussed above. We feel that it is much better to
allow market forces to determine rents and for governments to focus more on
quality of housing and measures that will increase the number of units available
on the market. Rent control accomplishes the exact opposite!